Da caravan project
So what does it gave my multiboxing with this new PC?
It's the ball! I commend myself thoroughly! My
7 teams each made at least one outlet and levels accumulate.
Slowly but surely, everyone makes his way to level 85.
Finally, apart from my ALLY for which it is not expected to exceed nordfendre, but that's another story ...
And beside that I do not forget my little guild to manage.
My weak point is the recruitment. And as we use color: we are not aficionados of the PVE HL casus but quiet, well we will not attract many people. But I hope that the handful of caravanners feel comfortable with us.
So, in addition leveler my characters there is also a guild to evolve and provide HF. Well, I'm not alone for that, fortunately. A guild, however small it is, is still not made a single individual.
But it is added to things I watch regularly, because ultimately what I like in this game, it's not down bosses, it's not me shake my noodle matting kikimeter to a pole. No, it motivates me more things remain to see my characters evolve. And since a guild cataclysm is a bit of a personal super. So here we
level 8.
Yes, it is not compared to the famous guilds type rocket, but not so frowned upon enrollment. And then it is better to move quietly but to follow the dark path of performance at the expense of pleasure.
Monday, February 21, 2011
Sunday, February 13, 2011
What Is Ring Pistom Of Bike
Are parents altruistic? Evidence in the 19th century.
The previous post
The previous post
Elisa on altruism has provoked an interesting discussion with our colleagues. In summary, we have kindly been called naive because we do not believe that selfishness is the sole determinant of economic choices. The debate, however, turned to the short counter with a late style "and with your children, you're selfless, right?". Not the best argument you may say, and I guess you can actually find great thinkers who have argued that selfishness could be motor behavior in relationships between parents and children (I also wonder if there is no bias, the great thinkers are they family like the others?), foremost among them Karl Marx, with and the historical materialism of its own:
Previously, The workman Sold His Own Labor power, Which he Disposed of nominally as a free agent. Now he sells wife and child. He has Become a slave dealer.
After reading this quote, the question arises
context and constraints on individuals. It is possible as stated by Parsons and Goldin (1989) that in some conditions comme celles prévalent au 19ème, les parents ne soient pas altruistes. Il est aussi possible que ces études nécessitent une révision comme celle récemment menée par Baskar et Gupsa intitulé "Were American Parents Really Selfish? Child Labor in the 19th Century" dont voici l'abstract:
Using the US Commissioner of Labor Survey of 1890, we examine household decisions and parental altruism vis-a-vis their children. Contrary to Parsons and Goldin (1989), we find that parental location choices were dictated by constraints rather than the desire to exploit child labor opportunities. We also find significant income effects on child labor supply, indicating that rising affluence Played important part year in The Secular decline of child labor. We find aussi thats the effects of childrens Income on Their Own consommation are weak, Oz Child Labor IS controlled for.
To avoid exaggerating the specialists, I shall say no more about this fascinating subject, so it is important to have a strong background in philosophy and sociology (perhaps even in biology *) to tell something really relevant. Feel free to leave links in comments (if you're altruistic ;-)) to enrich the knowledge of readers and writers of this blog.
F. Candau
* why I saw monkeys at the zoo yesterday he was seeking the chips on the back of his offspring, reciprocal altruism?
** we recommend bounded rationality for analysis indicated the theme of altruism.
Previously, The workman Sold His Own Labor power, Which he Disposed of nominally as a free agent. Now he sells wife and child. He has Become a slave dealer.
After reading this quote, the question arises
context and constraints on individuals. It is possible as stated by Parsons and Goldin (1989) that in some conditions comme celles prévalent au 19ème, les parents ne soient pas altruistes. Il est aussi possible que ces études nécessitent une révision comme celle récemment menée par Baskar et Gupsa intitulé "Were American Parents Really Selfish? Child Labor in the 19th Century" dont voici l'abstract:
Using the US Commissioner of Labor Survey of 1890, we examine household decisions and parental altruism vis-a-vis their children. Contrary to Parsons and Goldin (1989), we find that parental location choices were dictated by constraints rather than the desire to exploit child labor opportunities. We also find significant income effects on child labor supply, indicating that rising affluence Played important part year in The Secular decline of child labor. We find aussi thats the effects of childrens Income on Their Own consommation are weak, Oz Child Labor IS controlled for.
To avoid exaggerating the specialists, I shall say no more about this fascinating subject, so it is important to have a strong background in philosophy and sociology (perhaps even in biology *) to tell something really relevant. Feel free to leave links in comments (if you're altruistic ;-)) to enrich the knowledge of readers and writers of this blog.
F. Candau
* why I saw monkeys at the zoo yesterday he was seeking the chips on the back of his offspring, reciprocal altruism?
** we recommend bounded rationality for analysis indicated the theme of altruism.
Saturday, February 12, 2011
Wednesday, February 9, 2011
Usb Rs232 Rotronic 12.02.1086 Treiber
It has arrived! Run Run
Who did what to it?
My new PC teh!
Aaah!
He at least not when it crashes it sends me a simple picture on MSN or Skype.
It is quiet, fast, clean (it will not last).
short .. I have not bought a PC with two large area under it is a Dell that I customized on-line shop for a gaming machine, and it shows.
1st test: cross Ogrimmar has a great time attendance and a graphical configuration Ultra: fluidity barely flinches, it oscillates between 60 and 40ips depending on where I am. Yabon!
2nd test: a small fight in multibox. The hand is high configuration and clones on average. Again, Yabon.
(For those who are interrested http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=8H5ZotiZDhE even if there 's loss of quality with the conversion WMW)
More than reconfigure my keyboard, put the addons, MoW tweaking the settings, etc. ...
Who did what to it?
My new PC teh!
Aaah!
He at least not when it crashes it sends me a simple picture on MSN or Skype.
It is quiet, fast, clean (it will not last).
short .. I have not bought a PC with two large area under it is a Dell that I customized on-line shop for a gaming machine, and it shows.
1st test: cross Ogrimmar has a great time attendance and a graphical configuration Ultra: fluidity barely flinches, it oscillates between 60 and 40ips depending on where I am. Yabon!
2nd test: a small fight in multibox. The hand is high configuration and clones on average. Again, Yabon.
(For those who are interrested http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=8H5ZotiZDhE even if there 's loss of quality with the conversion WMW)
More than reconfigure my keyboard, put the addons, MoW tweaking the settings, etc. ...
Friday, February 4, 2011
Connecting External Drive To Lcd Tv
Altruistic or calculators? The case of intra-household
What motivates an individual to send money to his family, while he bears the costs associated with their migration? Is it pure altruism or is he waiting in return family and social recognition? The transfer behavior can be explained by a strategy they clear the migrant or bargaining power within the family, what is the role of social norms in this decision? How can we model the behavior of a migrant representative considering altruism, self interest, social pressures and implicit contracts interact in making its decision?
A microeconomic analysis of transfer is very important, particularly for developing countries (DCs): Why?
First, migration is a phenomenon that affects massively developing countries, whether internal migration (from rural to mostly urban) or migration across borders to more developed countries. Furthermore, financial transfers
reveal an issue more important than the country of origin is underdeveloped because it is characterized by low initial earnings, economic inequality and a strong income volatility (Rapoport and Docquier , 2006): thus private transfers by acting on these three characteristics have significant effects on developing countries and therefore deserve a special interest
Finally, market failures and credit insurance systems encourage more people to replace the banking and financial institutions, through domestic contracts are often implicit. This again is an element justifying the importance of remittances in developing countries, mostly affected by these failures.
Without addressing all the theoretical models that have been developed, we can present some reasons given in the literature to explain the behavior of microeconomic transfer.
I. A formulation without common measure: Altruism or Selfishness pure?
Since Becker (1974) we model the economic behavior through an altruistic utility function that depends not only on the consumption of the migrant but also the consumption of his family. We distinguish unilateral altruism only when the migrant seeks to satisfy the utility of other family members and bilateral or reciprocal altruism when his family is also seeking to maximize the utility of the migrant. The probability of transfer depends Revenue migrant, its degree of altruism and the level of income of other household members. Fairly simple, repeating ratings used by Rapoport and Docquier (2006), we consider an individual migrant noted (m), a household receiving the funds paid (h), which maximizes a utility function U, with an initial income R, and C consumption an amount transferred T. The formulation of the simple utility that follows is inspired by Stark (1985) which presented a model of pure altruism unilateral / or reciprocal
be altuisme the degree of the migrant and recipient household (reciprocity in altruism)
Vi (Ci) a positive and concave function of consumption. Assume that Vi (Ci) = Vi (R-T), which allows us to rewrite the utility function of the migrant:
By maximizing the latter function, we obtain the amount of transfers T * maximizes the value attached by the migrant and his household of origin. We get:
Vi (Ci, X) with i = m , h.
As pointed out by R & D (2006), it is assumed that members left behind will accept the exchange as long as the transfer offsets the cost of service, often estimated opportunity cost:
Thus bypassing the utility function for initial income and level of service provided by the recipient household transfer, we show that transfers increase with the level of service provided but react ambiguously to an increase in income household remained in place. Is the contribution of these theoretical developments initiated by Cox (1987) : Under certain conditions, higher income beneficiaries may cause an increase in transfers from the migrant.
To illustrate Cox (1987) took the case of intergenerational transfers and showed a positive relationship between transfers paid by the parents and the child's income: more income increases, its marginal utility consumption decreases and therefore it requires more remittances to offset the high cost of service to his parents. This relationship ultimately depends on the bargaining power of both parties. In this logic, a higher income the individual beneficiary or an increase in public transfers tend to increase the bargaining power of the person in question, which may require a higher amount of transfers from the migrant for a given level of service. Here we reconcile theory with a stylized fact already met: the rise of public transfers does not automatically drop private transfers (crowding out), because if we consider partially altruistic agents, the bargaining power of the beneficiary increases .
II. Strategic behavior revenue optimization
This notion of strategic behavior within the game theory is advanced by Stark (1985) and Stark and Wang (2002). Transfer to a simple objective: it can allow the migrant to increase its current income received by host region. When newly arrived migrants have higher levels of training and heterogeneous skills, the employer considers the individual productivity of an employee through the average productivity of its group. Thus, the migrant has an incentive to provide funds to unqualified relatives so they are not tempted to migrate and thus in turn reduce productivity group average. This theory is based on highly restrictive assumptions, assuming that individual productivity is not measurable in the short term and that the employer has an overview on the average productivity of the group (Rapoport and Docquier 1998 speaks of knowledge "pre Anthropology -required "). Stark concludes that only the skilled should find an advantage to migrate. Stark and Wang (2002) and within the first hypothesis assumes that the employer can quickly see the individual productivity of the migrant. In this context, the skilled migrant seeking to maximize its income by assuming that there will be more non-qualified the labor market, the more his own remuneration will be increased. Thus, transfers are used to finance the cost of migration of unskilled relatives arriving on the same labor market and highlight the highest qualification of the first wave of migrants.
More formally, we set m and h m with potential migrants who are more qualified. Pi is the proportion of productivity of h in terms of productivity m. If both remain in the region of origin, the remuneration is clear: win Rh m and h wins:
If the individual migrates m alone, the migrant receives remuneration equal to his marginal product, or Rom, but if it is joined by h, then its earnings decline in the average productivity of both migrant
If remittances strategic intervene so that the individual unqualified am an income at least equivalent to what would have obtained if migrated:
and that the migrant does not see his income reduced by income:
then transfers encourage unqualified to remain in their region of origin and the migrant can maximize its income. According
Stark, this approach allows strategic transfers to question some studies that overestimate the share of altruism in explaining transfers. Indeed, predictions of such models are very close to those obtained in a migrant's altruistic, but the underlying reasons are not the same.
And so rather than seeing the migrant as a pure altruist or a strategist, one who takes his decision, we consider an interaction of social and family influence in his decision making?
Family and Social Interactions in the decision of the individual
I. Insurance and moral hazard.
Developing countries are particularly affected by the volatility of their income, intrinsically linked to their dependence vis-à-vis agriculture and weak systems of risk pooling. Indeed, in the absence of credit market and insurance , poor countries become more vulnerable to price shocks and hence income and can be found in the migration and financial transfers, a means of pooling risks. Thus, as pointed out several studies, it is possible to observe the arrangements of families (implicit contracts) to send some members to urban areas or abroad in order to pool the risk agricultural and eligible for re-allocation of resources potential (Stark and Levhari, 1982 Rozenzweig, 1988, Lambert 1994).
We study a household with two successive periods, consisting of two individuals h and m receiving income ₀ initial R, which in the second period may vary randomly R1min up with probability p and with probability p R1max-1. Rural income is volatile and uncertain. The two agents have the same utility function, because the uncertainty of farm incomes affect everyone the same way.
One of the two individuals decide to migrate in the second period to obtain a stable income. The cost of migration can not be supported by one person shall not be less than the initial joint household income (Ro \u0026lt;2RO). The burden of the cost of migration is supported by two distribution of costs should be decided in the first period, taking into account the volatility of income in the second half. Rapoport and Docquier formalizes the implicit family contract as follows:
where delta is the share of the cost of migration (c) supported by the migrant himself, Tp and T1-p are transfers according that the prosperity of the period, lambda is the "Family weight" of the individual who does not migrate (bargaining power) and Vh its level of utility in the first period. Thus, the implicit contract provides that the value attached to the two individuals be maximized under the constraint of financing the cost of migration and economic context in decision making.
The two utility functions to maximize can be written:
The theory of insurance provides very close predictions of the theory of altruistic migrant. Nevertheless, time horizons are different, because in this theoretical framework, the transfer decision is sequential in time and temporal effects are not the same.
II. Investment and credit market failures
Lucas and Stark (1985) studied the behavior of the individual in the context of Botswana, by developing a model they call "tempered altruism" or "enlightened selfishness" demonstrating the dualism of human behavior. Very simply, it is assumed that transfers are a contractual arrangement agreed by the migrant and his family of origin, contract inter-temporal and reciprocal. Migrants from urban areas are often more educated and better trained than the family members remained in the field. But the initial cost of education and the cost of migration is often borne by the family, and in fact partly justifies future transfers of the migrant: it is a loan repayment at interest (Cox & Jimenez 1992, Cox, Eser & Jimenez 1998, Ilahi & Jafarey 1999). The migrant compensates for the absence of credit market and the family invests in the education of one member to obtain a future pension. That's intertemporal arbitrage where every part of the contract maximizes its own utility but in which social norms and inter-generational coming interfere choice.
III. Bargaining power and volume of shipments
Aisa, and Larramona Andaluz (2011) have developed a negotiation model which aims to the volumes transferred by a bargaining game between the migrant and his family. The most direct consequence of this type of model is the demonstration of a relationship between nonmonotonic revenues of the two 'parties' and the amount of remittances. Already Cox et al. (1998) had introduced the important concept of bargaining power between the generations. Such modeling requires defining the determinant of the bargaining power of members of a family: it is primarily a latent threat "Threat Point" as a threat of divorce or break the implicit contract between two parties . The authors choose a cooperative environment and a Nash solution to characterize their bargaining model. So the transfer volumes determined by utility maximization are Pareto efficient.
The optimization model is written as the migrant (m) should consider the usefulness of his family (h), with a share of altruism in its decision, within budget constraints of h and m :
Q with the level of family service rendered by non-migrants, which costs them pQ and the degree of altruism. Finally, after resolution of the program determining the optimal levels of service * Q Record and Cm * and Ch * consumption optimal, the optimal solution for the amount transferred T * written:
or the volume of transfers associated with the situation Pareto efficient. At this level, no bargaining power is even built. Indeed, the first step according to the authors, is to define the critical point or the status quo of the negotiation process. In the literature it is often assumed that divorce or the breakdown of the domestic contract is the threat (non-cooperative solution) that determines the bargaining power and the distribution of welfare between the migrant and his family. In their model, the authors assume that this point is characterized by the complete absence of altruism (beta = 0), no transfer is made and each maximizes his own utility. the solution is not cooperative. Thus, during the negotiation process, the solution of Nash General Equilibrium is achieved by maximizing the following:
with theta ∈ [0,1] the bargaining power of migrants and (1-theta) than his family, exogenous parameters in the model (De Haas, 2007). Thus, once the first order conditions specified, the utility levels optimized, the authors obtain the transfer amount T * that maximizes this utility as part of a negotiation process.
This result reinforces the idea that the migrant has more bargaining power, the lower volumes shipped is important. Conversely, the relationship between the degree of altruism, migrant's income and transfers are more ambiguous, the sign of the derivatives just depends on the bargaining power, but also levels of utility in non-cooperative situation. The authors finally show that the relationship between income and migrant remittances is a non monotonic function.
IV. Mixed models
authors have sought to model the transfer behavior in a less categorical, mixing incentives seen so far. For example, we may assume that the implicit contracts family will meet both a motive for investment (and therefore interest loan) and a pattern of insurance and risk diversification. The very notions of altruism and selfishness are intertwined automatically under the influence of social norms and attention directed to features of society of origin. Domestic contracts
whether implied or otherwise, are often subject to strategic decisions that affect individual motivations of the original transfers. Thus, Chami, Fullenkamp & Jahjah, 2005 and Naiditch & Vranceanu, 2009 show that to move mechanically causes an asymmetry of information that pushes migrant family or playing a dominant position to influence the transfer decision. Naiditch & Vranceanu, 2009 have developed an original model called Signal, which is to assume that asymmetric information situation, the migrant uses amounts transferred to signal social success to his family, which has no information to judge. Thus, transfers are no longer a monotonic function of the migrant's income, since in a precarious situation, wanting to ensure a high social status in his home region would contract its disposable income to send transfer rates.
Library
- Aisa, and Larramona Andaluz (2011) How does bargaining power affects remittances? Economic Modelling, January-March 2011
- Becker, Gary S. 1974. A Theory of Social Interactions. Journal of Political Economy, 82, 6, pp. 1063-1093.
- Chami, R., C. Fullenkamp and S. Jahjah (2003): Are immigrant remittance flows a source of capital for development, IMF Working No 03/89.
- Cox, D. (1987): Motives for private transfers, Journal of Political Economy, 95(3): 508-46.
- Cox, D. and E. Jimenez (1992): Social security and private transfers in a developing country: the case of Peru, World Bank Economic Review, 6(1): 155-69.
- Cox, D., Z. Eser and E. Jimenez (1998): Motives for private transfers over the life cycle: An analytical framework and evidence for Peru, Journal of Development Economics, 55: 57-80.
- de Haas, Hein. 2006. Migration, Remittances and Regional Development in Southern Morocco. Geoforum, 37, pp. 565 580.
- Docquier, F. and H. Rapoport (1998): Are migrant minorities strategically self-selected?, Journal of Population Economics, 11: 579-88.
- Docquier, F. and H. Rapoport (2006): The Economics of migrants' remittances
- Foster, A.D. and M.R. Rosenzweig (2001): Imperfect commitment, altruism, and the family: evidence from transfer behavior in low-income rural areas, Review of Economics and Statistics, LXXXIII (3): 389-407.
- Funkhouser, E. (1995): Remittances from international migration: a comparison of El Salvador and Nicaragua, Review of Economics and Statistics, 77, 1: 137-46.
- Ilahi, N. and S. Jafarey (1999): Guestworker migration, remittances and the extended family: evidence from Pakistan, Journal of Development Economics, 58: 485-512.
- Lambert, S. (1994): La migration comme instrument de diversification intrafamiliale des risques. Application au cas de la Cote d’Ivoire, Revue d’Economie du Développement, 02: 3-38.
- Lucas, R.E.B. (1987): Emigration to South Africa’s mines, American Economic Review, 77, 3: 313-30.
- Lucas, R.E.B. (1997): Internal migration in developing countries, in M.R. Rosenzweig and O.Stark, eds.: Handbook of Family and Population Economics, Amsterdam, North Holland. Chapter 13, Vol. 1.B, pp. 721-98.
- Lucas, R.E.B. and O. Stark (1985): Motivations to remit: Evidence from Botswana, Journal of Political Economy, 93, 5: 901-18.
Naiditch, Claire & Vranceanu, Radu, 2009.Remittances as a social status signaling device, DR 09015, ESSEC Research Center, ESSEC Business School
- Rosenzweig, M.R. (1988a): Risk, implicit contracts and the family in rural areas of low income countries, Economic Journal, 393: 1148-70.
- Stark, O. and D. Levhari (1982): On migration and risk in LDCs, Economic Development and Cultural Change, 31: 191-6
- Stark. Oded, et Wang. 2002. Migration Dynamics. Economic Letters, 76, pp. 159-164
A microeconomic analysis of transfer is very important, particularly for developing countries (DCs): Why?
First, migration is a phenomenon that affects massively developing countries, whether internal migration (from rural to mostly urban) or migration across borders to more developed countries. Furthermore, financial transfers
reveal an issue more important than the country of origin is underdeveloped because it is characterized by low initial earnings, economic inequality and a strong income volatility (Rapoport and Docquier , 2006): thus private transfers by acting on these three characteristics have significant effects on developing countries and therefore deserve a special interest
Finally, market failures and credit insurance systems encourage more people to replace the banking and financial institutions, through domestic contracts are often implicit. This again is an element justifying the importance of remittances in developing countries, mostly affected by these failures.
Without addressing all the theoretical models that have been developed, we can present some reasons given in the literature to explain the behavior of microeconomic transfer.
I. A formulation without common measure: Altruism or Selfishness pure?
Since Becker (1974) we model the economic behavior through an altruistic utility function that depends not only on the consumption of the migrant but also the consumption of his family. We distinguish unilateral altruism only when the migrant seeks to satisfy the utility of other family members and bilateral or reciprocal altruism when his family is also seeking to maximize the utility of the migrant. The probability of transfer depends Revenue migrant, its degree of altruism and the level of income of other household members. Fairly simple, repeating ratings used by Rapoport and Docquier (2006), we consider an individual migrant noted (m), a household receiving the funds paid (h), which maximizes a utility function U, with an initial income R, and C consumption an amount transferred T. The formulation of the simple utility that follows is inspired by Stark (1985) which presented a model of pure altruism unilateral / or reciprocal
be altuisme the degree of the migrant and recipient household (reciprocity in altruism)
Vi (Ci) a positive and concave function of consumption. Assume that Vi (Ci) = Vi (R-T), which allows us to rewrite the utility function of the migrant:
By maximizing the latter function, we obtain the amount of transfers T * maximizes the value attached by the migrant and his household of origin. We get:
So the optimal transfer depends positively on income and the degree of altruism of the migrant and the recipient's income negatively. In this context of pure altruism, we can add if the initial income increases by one, the optimal transfer increases as a unit:
This very restrictive assumption forces us to quickly release the theory of pure altruism. Indeed, as pointed Funkhouser (1995), empirical studies contradict this perfect proportionality between the change in income and migrant transfers paid.
There is a theory that is totally opposed to model transfer behavior as an exchange , Thus aiming to serve the interest of the migrant. Thus, by paying money to the migrant relatives trying to acquire services in return (members left behind have to deal with his elders and children, or manage its heritage ... etc.). This configuration transfers is advanced by Cox (1987) Cox, Eiser and Jimenez (1998) and Rapoport and Docquier (2006).
Suppose transfers are paid to buy a level of service provided X, the utility functions become based on levels of consumption and services in the country of origin Vi (Ci, X) with i = m , h.
As pointed out by R & D (2006), it is assumed that members left behind will accept the exchange as long as the transfer offsets the cost of service, often estimated opportunity cost:
To illustrate Cox (1987) took the case of intergenerational transfers and showed a positive relationship between transfers paid by the parents and the child's income: more income increases, its marginal utility consumption decreases and therefore it requires more remittances to offset the high cost of service to his parents. This relationship ultimately depends on the bargaining power of both parties. In this logic, a higher income the individual beneficiary or an increase in public transfers tend to increase the bargaining power of the person in question, which may require a higher amount of transfers from the migrant for a given level of service. Here we reconcile theory with a stylized fact already met: the rise of public transfers does not automatically drop private transfers (crowding out), because if we consider partially altruistic agents, the bargaining power of the beneficiary increases .
II. Strategic behavior revenue optimization
This notion of strategic behavior within the game theory is advanced by Stark (1985) and Stark and Wang (2002). Transfer to a simple objective: it can allow the migrant to increase its current income received by host region. When newly arrived migrants have higher levels of training and heterogeneous skills, the employer considers the individual productivity of an employee through the average productivity of its group. Thus, the migrant has an incentive to provide funds to unqualified relatives so they are not tempted to migrate and thus in turn reduce productivity group average. This theory is based on highly restrictive assumptions, assuming that individual productivity is not measurable in the short term and that the employer has an overview on the average productivity of the group (Rapoport and Docquier 1998 speaks of knowledge "pre Anthropology -required "). Stark concludes that only the skilled should find an advantage to migrate. Stark and Wang (2002) and within the first hypothesis assumes that the employer can quickly see the individual productivity of the migrant. In this context, the skilled migrant seeking to maximize its income by assuming that there will be more non-qualified the labor market, the more his own remuneration will be increased. Thus, transfers are used to finance the cost of migration of unskilled relatives arriving on the same labor market and highlight the highest qualification of the first wave of migrants.
More formally, we set m and h m with potential migrants who are more qualified. Pi is the proportion of productivity of h in terms of productivity m. If both remain in the region of origin, the remuneration is clear: win Rh m and h wins:
If the individual migrates m alone, the migrant receives remuneration equal to his marginal product, or Rom, but if it is joined by h, then its earnings decline in the average productivity of both migrant
If remittances strategic intervene so that the individual unqualified am an income at least equivalent to what would have obtained if migrated:
Stark, this approach allows strategic transfers to question some studies that overestimate the share of altruism in explaining transfers. Indeed, predictions of such models are very close to those obtained in a migrant's altruistic, but the underlying reasons are not the same.
And so rather than seeing the migrant as a pure altruist or a strategist, one who takes his decision, we consider an interaction of social and family influence in his decision making?
Family and Social Interactions in the decision of the individual
I. Insurance and moral hazard.
Developing countries are particularly affected by the volatility of their income, intrinsically linked to their dependence vis-à-vis agriculture and weak systems of risk pooling. Indeed, in the absence of credit market and insurance , poor countries become more vulnerable to price shocks and hence income and can be found in the migration and financial transfers, a means of pooling risks. Thus, as pointed out several studies, it is possible to observe the arrangements of families (implicit contracts) to send some members to urban areas or abroad in order to pool the risk agricultural and eligible for re-allocation of resources potential (Stark and Levhari, 1982 Rozenzweig, 1988, Lambert 1994).
We study a household with two successive periods, consisting of two individuals h and m receiving income ₀ initial R, which in the second period may vary randomly R1min up with probability p and with probability p R1max-1. Rural income is volatile and uncertain. The two agents have the same utility function, because the uncertainty of farm incomes affect everyone the same way.
One of the two individuals decide to migrate in the second period to obtain a stable income. The cost of migration can not be supported by one person shall not be less than the initial joint household income (Ro
where delta is the share of the cost of migration (c) supported by the migrant himself, Tp and T1-p are transfers according that the prosperity of the period, lambda is the "Family weight" of the individual who does not migrate (bargaining power) and Vh its level of utility in the first period. Thus, the implicit contract provides that the value attached to the two individuals be maximized under the constraint of financing the cost of migration and economic context in decision making.
The two utility functions to maximize can be written:
The theory of insurance provides very close predictions of the theory of altruistic migrant. Nevertheless, time horizons are different, because in this theoretical framework, the transfer decision is sequential in time and temporal effects are not the same.
II. Investment and credit market failures
Lucas and Stark (1985) studied the behavior of the individual in the context of Botswana, by developing a model they call "tempered altruism" or "enlightened selfishness" demonstrating the dualism of human behavior. Very simply, it is assumed that transfers are a contractual arrangement agreed by the migrant and his family of origin, contract inter-temporal and reciprocal. Migrants from urban areas are often more educated and better trained than the family members remained in the field. But the initial cost of education and the cost of migration is often borne by the family, and in fact partly justifies future transfers of the migrant: it is a loan repayment at interest (Cox & Jimenez 1992, Cox, Eser & Jimenez 1998, Ilahi & Jafarey 1999). The migrant compensates for the absence of credit market and the family invests in the education of one member to obtain a future pension. That's intertemporal arbitrage where every part of the contract maximizes its own utility but in which social norms and inter-generational coming interfere choice.
III. Bargaining power and volume of shipments
Aisa, and Larramona Andaluz (2011) have developed a negotiation model which aims to the volumes transferred by a bargaining game between the migrant and his family. The most direct consequence of this type of model is the demonstration of a relationship between nonmonotonic revenues of the two 'parties' and the amount of remittances. Already Cox et al. (1998) had introduced the important concept of bargaining power between the generations. Such modeling requires defining the determinant of the bargaining power of members of a family: it is primarily a latent threat "Threat Point" as a threat of divorce or break the implicit contract between two parties . The authors choose a cooperative environment and a Nash solution to characterize their bargaining model. So the transfer volumes determined by utility maximization are Pareto efficient.
The optimization model is written as the migrant (m) should consider the usefulness of his family (h), with a share of altruism in its decision, within budget constraints of h and m :
Q with the level of family service rendered by non-migrants, which costs them pQ and the degree of altruism. Finally, after resolution of the program determining the optimal levels of service * Q Record and Cm * and Ch * consumption optimal, the optimal solution for the amount transferred T * written:
or the volume of transfers associated with the situation Pareto efficient. At this level, no bargaining power is even built. Indeed, the first step according to the authors, is to define the critical point or the status quo of the negotiation process. In the literature it is often assumed that divorce or the breakdown of the domestic contract is the threat (non-cooperative solution) that determines the bargaining power and the distribution of welfare between the migrant and his family. In their model, the authors assume that this point is characterized by the complete absence of altruism (beta = 0), no transfer is made and each maximizes his own utility. the solution is not cooperative. Thus, during the negotiation process, the solution of Nash General Equilibrium is achieved by maximizing the following:
with theta ∈ [0,1] the bargaining power of migrants and (1-theta) than his family, exogenous parameters in the model (De Haas, 2007). Thus, once the first order conditions specified, the utility levels optimized, the authors obtain the transfer amount T * that maximizes this utility as part of a negotiation process.
This result reinforces the idea that the migrant has more bargaining power, the lower volumes shipped is important. Conversely, the relationship between the degree of altruism, migrant's income and transfers are more ambiguous, the sign of the derivatives just depends on the bargaining power, but also levels of utility in non-cooperative situation. The authors finally show that the relationship between income and migrant remittances is a non monotonic function.
IV. Mixed models
authors have sought to model the transfer behavior in a less categorical, mixing incentives seen so far. For example, we may assume that the implicit contracts family will meet both a motive for investment (and therefore interest loan) and a pattern of insurance and risk diversification. The very notions of altruism and selfishness are intertwined automatically under the influence of social norms and attention directed to features of society of origin. Domestic contracts
whether implied or otherwise, are often subject to strategic decisions that affect individual motivations of the original transfers. Thus, Chami, Fullenkamp & Jahjah, 2005 and Naiditch & Vranceanu, 2009 show that to move mechanically causes an asymmetry of information that pushes migrant family or playing a dominant position to influence the transfer decision. Naiditch & Vranceanu, 2009 have developed an original model called Signal, which is to assume that asymmetric information situation, the migrant uses amounts transferred to signal social success to his family, which has no information to judge. Thus, transfers are no longer a monotonic function of the migrant's income, since in a precarious situation, wanting to ensure a high social status in his home region would contract its disposable income to send transfer rates.
Library
- Aisa, and Larramona Andaluz (2011) How does bargaining power affects remittances? Economic Modelling, January-March 2011
- Becker, Gary S. 1974. A Theory of Social Interactions. Journal of Political Economy, 82, 6, pp. 1063-1093.
- Chami, R., C. Fullenkamp and S. Jahjah (2003): Are immigrant remittance flows a source of capital for development, IMF Working No 03/89.
- Cox, D. (1987): Motives for private transfers, Journal of Political Economy, 95(3): 508-46.
- Cox, D. and E. Jimenez (1992): Social security and private transfers in a developing country: the case of Peru, World Bank Economic Review, 6(1): 155-69.
- Cox, D., Z. Eser and E. Jimenez (1998): Motives for private transfers over the life cycle: An analytical framework and evidence for Peru, Journal of Development Economics, 55: 57-80.
- de Haas, Hein. 2006. Migration, Remittances and Regional Development in Southern Morocco. Geoforum, 37, pp. 565 580.
- Docquier, F. and H. Rapoport (1998): Are migrant minorities strategically self-selected?, Journal of Population Economics, 11: 579-88.
- Docquier, F. and H. Rapoport (2006): The Economics of migrants' remittances
- Foster, A.D. and M.R. Rosenzweig (2001): Imperfect commitment, altruism, and the family: evidence from transfer behavior in low-income rural areas, Review of Economics and Statistics, LXXXIII (3): 389-407.
- Funkhouser, E. (1995): Remittances from international migration: a comparison of El Salvador and Nicaragua, Review of Economics and Statistics, 77, 1: 137-46.
- Ilahi, N. and S. Jafarey (1999): Guestworker migration, remittances and the extended family: evidence from Pakistan, Journal of Development Economics, 58: 485-512.
- Lambert, S. (1994): La migration comme instrument de diversification intrafamiliale des risques. Application au cas de la Cote d’Ivoire, Revue d’Economie du Développement, 02: 3-38.
- Lucas, R.E.B. (1987): Emigration to South Africa’s mines, American Economic Review, 77, 3: 313-30.
- Lucas, R.E.B. (1997): Internal migration in developing countries, in M.R. Rosenzweig and O.Stark, eds.: Handbook of Family and Population Economics, Amsterdam, North Holland. Chapter 13, Vol. 1.B, pp. 721-98.
- Lucas, R.E.B. and O. Stark (1985): Motivations to remit: Evidence from Botswana, Journal of Political Economy, 93, 5: 901-18.
Naiditch, Claire & Vranceanu, Radu, 2009.Remittances as a social status signaling device, DR 09015, ESSEC Research Center, ESSEC Business School
- Rosenzweig, M.R. (1988a): Risk, implicit contracts and the family in rural areas of low income countries, Economic Journal, 393: 1148-70.
- Stark, O. and D. Levhari (1982): On migration and risk in LDCs, Economic Development and Cultural Change, 31: 191-6
- Stark. Oded, et Wang. 2002. Migration Dynamics. Economic Letters, 76, pp. 159-164
For Disconect Telephone Sample Letter
Deathwing
is clearly not my style of music but hey, the video quality is good and the girls have very nice voice although the human and the Goblin are a bit below, you give them the benefit of the doubt for not having a good microphone.
is clearly not my style of music but hey, the video quality is good and the girls have very nice voice although the human and the Goblin are a bit below, you give them the benefit of the doubt for not having a good microphone.
Friday, January 28, 2011
Ladies Shoes Blog Post A Comment
Basics Many of WoW
Mnesys The friend gave us a video tutorial on the forum dual-boxing.fr.
So here it is!
Mnesys The friend gave us a video tutorial on the forum dual-boxing.fr.
So here it is!
Tuesday, January 25, 2011
White Mucus A Day Before Period
Alarming rise in agricultural prices
Agricultural prices again reach record highs.
In 2007-2008 the situation had been extreme, with increases ranging up to 130% on wheat and smaller increases on other agricultural products, but still great for those who live with a few dollars a day.
Because obviously it is the poorest who are hardest hit, especially since they spend a major portion of their budgets to agricultural products.
This situation had led to riots around the world, and this scenario may repeat itself ...
In the past, countries have erected trade barrirères (taxes) so that exports are redirected to the local market, where more than supply and therefore lower prices. The urban consumer is clearly the winner of this policy but the rural producer loses (it could higher prices for export). The following year, the probability that the producer improve its technical and investment is lower, so in the medium term the problem of a lack of production is not resolved because the "price signal" has been broken .
Obviously we need to find a solution, protectionism is not one.
especially since these policies have greatly asymmetric effects ... When India decided to limit its exports of rice by controlling the price on its local market because it produces a lot but this also means that a massive part of the supply market disappears Comprehensive, where an explosion in world which severely affects small importers. Today
these non-cooperative policies are still fashionable and it is feared they will remain for internal political reasons, it is urgent to find another solution for that agricultural prices is lower and less volatile.
In 2007-2008 the situation had been extreme, with increases ranging up to 130% on wheat and smaller increases on other agricultural products, but still great for those who live with a few dollars a day.
This situation had led to riots around the world, and this scenario may repeat itself ...
In the past, countries have erected trade barrirères (taxes) so that exports are redirected to the local market, where more than supply and therefore lower prices. The urban consumer is clearly the winner of this policy but the rural producer loses (it could higher prices for export). The following year, the probability that the producer improve its technical and investment is lower, so in the medium term the problem of a lack of production is not resolved because the "price signal" has been broken .
Obviously we need to find a solution, protectionism is not one.
especially since these policies have greatly asymmetric effects ... When India decided to limit its exports of rice by controlling the price on its local market because it produces a lot but this also means that a massive part of the supply market disappears Comprehensive, where an explosion in world which severely affects small importers. Today
these non-cooperative policies are still fashionable and it is feared they will remain for internal political reasons, it is urgent to find another solution for that agricultural prices is lower and less volatile.
Thursday, January 20, 2011
Tex Capacity Input Stack Size
iceberg costs, but affected (yet) sunk!
in international economics and space there is an assumption that good practice is that only a fraction of the exported good to happen destination because of trade costs.
The original idea back to von Thunen. He gave the example of a plow pulled by a horse oats on a long journey during which the exporter and then in the commodity exported to feed his nag.
Samuelson looter in engineering, took up the idea and changed the picture, part of the iceberg melts during his trip, this part is the cost iceberg.
Schematically, the price of a property that crosses a border like a stair step, more or less depending on the cost iceberg.
If the price of local production costs i pi, then the price of delivery j will be t * Ft.
If this hypothesis has little suffering the assaults of researchers is probably for practical reasons, as evidenced by Paul Krugman:
"The major justification for the Iceberg Observational Assumption Is Not Gold Analytical empirical goal, I'm his It Is to trick Technical 'Reasons employed for modeling of `convenience', thereby [...] Avoiding The Need to model year Additional industrie '(Krugman 1998, 165)."
iceberg costs have been introduced in 80 years not to confuse the issue at the time it was necessary to understand international trade imperfect competition, distiinguer effects models with increasing returns and monopolistic competition from those obtained in this modeling competition ... brief was a research strategy which allowed to look elsewhere (there was still modeling incorporating an industry Transportation eco inter, see especially Falvey (1976)).
But lately this assumption is lifted and she has good reason to be because if it is acceptable as an ad-valorem equivalent for firms operating in a competitive market, the equivalence disappears in models with monopolistic competition * and becomes untenable if one considers the transportation costs.
It should be noted that many authors speak of the iceberg as costs including transport costs. Or to include transportation, we must at least incorporate the distance. Let us turn to Fujita et al. (1999) to understand how to relate (or not) costs iceberg in the distance. According to these authors, if the value of goods produced locally is Vi then delivered value, denoted Vd is :
where tij represents the part lost en route and dij distance, this implies that the distance elasticity the delivered value decreases steadily, kilometers after kilometers:
Because of this constancy that Grossman called the iceberg cost technology for "transportation of tomatoes ... and even these perishable goods it is doubtful that the decline in value is constant. We know that such firms do not have the same behavior when space is introduced: some export to distant markets for higher quality products than they sell locally (Alchian and Allen (1964)). Implicitly
(especially in theoretical papers) it is sometimes regarded as iceberg trade costs are a monotonic function of transport costs. But the relationship may be nonmonotonic. A drop in transportation can certainly cause an increase in the value of exported but in the second time this fall may allow exporters to invest in higher quality goods for which trade costs may be higher, resulting in bell curve linking trade and transportation costs (Duranton and Storper (2008)). I will not discuss the research that attempt to explain the surprising result that the distance has an ever more important in our society and I refer to Belgodère and Noblet (2010) for a summary explanation of the puzzle before their connecting coordination costs and Specialization.
But that's not all, McCann (2005) and McCann and Fingleton (2007) invite us to look more closely at these costs by studying the iceberg original price and arrival. Let
whose first and second derivatives we easily show that the price delivered is a convex function of the distance. This is a strong assumption for transport economists that show that there are economies of scale and distance in transport, at least in some industries, the relationship may be concave. To avoid the fact that the lost portion of the property is constant with distance and introduce economies of scale, Fingleton (2005) proposes using a power function of transport costs Tij:
With this type function of density, agglomeration forces are exacerbated and as regards trade, gravity equation used to estimate is biased (Rudolph (2010)). But this type of function lacks microfoundations. Many efforts are still needed but the cost analysis with endogenous trade are already showing results in terms of interressants location choices and well being (see Matsuyama (2007) Gaigné Behrens and Thisse (2009)). To conclude, I can not resist the pleasure of quoting Article Behrens and Robert-Nicoud (2010):
We Believe It Is Time to start to think about transportation in gravement NEG. Transportation Costs Prices are Largely Which are set in competitive markets and Imperfectly Which corresponds to demand and supply shocks. The recent trade collapse Provides a neat illustration: the Baltic Dry Index (BDI) Fell Between May 20, 2008 and December 5, 2008 by a whopping 94%, and this May Have Been The burst of The Biggest of all bubbles. Technology That Dramatically Did Not change over Such A Short Period, supply and demand did ". [...] Maybe the iceberg Will not Turn Out to Be That Bad After All Assumption year, But It Would Be reassuring to know why and how this short-cut Can Be used.
Briefly iceberg raise the hypothesis should provide a better understanding of the geography of trade that has an effect on our purchasing power.
F. Candau
* See Cole (2009). Moreover, the author presents a model for the Melitz (2003) but with a utility function quasi-linear (to evacuate the income effects) and with hétérognéneité firms that is due to fixed costs and not marginal costs (for more stick to reality). This model with trade costs non-reciprocal (unlike Melitz (2003)) opens with an analysis of strategic trade policies. See on this excellent paper and Südekum Pflüger (2009) who study strategic interactions on subsidies to entry.
Bibliography
The original idea back to von Thunen. He gave the example of a plow pulled by a horse oats on a long journey during which the exporter and then in the commodity exported to feed his nag.
Samuelson looter in engineering, took up the idea and changed the picture, part of the iceberg melts during his trip, this part is the cost iceberg.
Schematically, the price of a property that crosses a border like a stair step, more or less depending on the cost iceberg.
If the price of local production costs i pi, then the price of delivery j will be t * Ft.
If this hypothesis has little suffering the assaults of researchers is probably for practical reasons, as evidenced by Paul Krugman:
"The major justification for the Iceberg Observational Assumption Is Not Gold Analytical empirical goal, I'm his It Is to trick Technical 'Reasons employed for modeling of `convenience', thereby [...] Avoiding The Need to model year Additional industrie '(Krugman 1998, 165)."
iceberg costs have been introduced in 80 years not to confuse the issue at the time it was necessary to understand international trade imperfect competition, distiinguer effects models with increasing returns and monopolistic competition from those obtained in this modeling competition ... brief was a research strategy which allowed to look elsewhere (there was still modeling incorporating an industry Transportation eco inter, see especially Falvey (1976)).
But lately this assumption is lifted and she has good reason to be because if it is acceptable as an ad-valorem equivalent for firms operating in a competitive market, the equivalence disappears in models with monopolistic competition * and becomes untenable if one considers the transportation costs.
It should be noted that many authors speak of the iceberg as costs including transport costs. Or to include transportation, we must at least incorporate the distance. Let us turn to Fujita et al. (1999) to understand how to relate (or not) costs iceberg in the distance. According to these authors, if the value of goods produced locally is Vi then delivered value, denoted Vd is
where tij represents the part lost en route and dij distance, this implies that the distance elasticity the delivered value decreases steadily, kilometers after kilometers:
Because of this constancy that Grossman called the iceberg cost technology for "transportation of tomatoes ... and even these perishable goods it is doubtful that the decline in value is constant. We know that such firms do not have the same behavior when space is introduced: some export to distant markets for higher quality products than they sell locally (Alchian and Allen (1964)). Implicitly
(especially in theoretical papers) it is sometimes regarded as iceberg trade costs are a monotonic function of transport costs. But the relationship may be nonmonotonic. A drop in transportation can certainly cause an increase in the value of exported but in the second time this fall may allow exporters to invest in higher quality goods for which trade costs may be higher, resulting in bell curve linking trade and transportation costs (Duranton and Storper (2008)). I will not discuss the research that attempt to explain the surprising result that the distance has an ever more important in our society and I refer to Belgodère and Noblet (2010) for a summary explanation of the puzzle before their connecting coordination costs and Specialization.
But that's not all, McCann (2005) and McCann and Fingleton (2007) invite us to look more closely at these costs by studying the iceberg original price and arrival. Let
whose first and second derivatives we easily show that the price delivered is a convex function of the distance. This is a strong assumption for transport economists that show that there are economies of scale and distance in transport, at least in some industries, the relationship may be concave. To avoid the fact that the lost portion of the property is constant with distance and introduce economies of scale, Fingleton (2005) proposes using a power function of transport costs Tij:
With this type function of density, agglomeration forces are exacerbated and as regards trade, gravity equation used to estimate is biased (Rudolph (2010)). But this type of function lacks microfoundations. Many efforts are still needed but the cost analysis with endogenous trade are already showing results in terms of interressants location choices and well being (see Matsuyama (2007) Gaigné Behrens and Thisse (2009)). To conclude, I can not resist the pleasure of quoting Article Behrens and Robert-Nicoud (2010):
We Believe It Is Time to start to think about transportation in gravement NEG. Transportation Costs Prices are Largely Which are set in competitive markets and Imperfectly Which corresponds to demand and supply shocks. The recent trade collapse Provides a neat illustration: the Baltic Dry Index (BDI) Fell Between May 20, 2008 and December 5, 2008 by a whopping 94%, and this May Have Been The burst of The Biggest of all bubbles. Technology That Dramatically Did Not change over Such A Short Period, supply and demand did ". [...] Maybe the iceberg Will not Turn Out to Be That Bad After All Assumption year, But It Would Be reassuring to know why and how this short-cut Can Be used.
Briefly iceberg raise the hypothesis should provide a better understanding of the geography of trade that has an effect on our purchasing power.
F. Candau
* See Cole (2009). Moreover, the author presents a model for the Melitz (2003) but with a utility function quasi-linear (to evacuate the income effects) and with hétérognéneité firms that is due to fixed costs and not marginal costs (for more stick to reality). This model with trade costs non-reciprocal (unlike Melitz (2003)) opens with an analysis of strategic trade policies. See on this excellent paper and Südekum Pflüger (2009) who study strategic interactions on subsidies to entry.
Bibliography
- Alchian, Armen A., and William R. Allen (1964) University Economics (Belmont, CA: Wadsworth)
- Behrens, K. C. And J.-F. Thisse Gaigné (2009) Industry location and Welfare Costs When transportation are endogenous, Journal of Urban Economics 65, 195-208.
- Cole, M, 2009.The Choice of Modeling Firm Heterogeneity and Trade Restrictions. University College Dublin Centre for Economic Research.
- Duranton, G., Storper, M., 2008. Rising trade costs? Agglomeration and trade with endogenous transaction costs. Canadian Journal of Economics 41 (1), 291(319).
- Falvey, Rodney E. 1976. "Transport Costs in the Pure Theory of International Trade," Econ. J. 86:343, pp. 536-50.
- Matsuyama, K. (2007) Beyond icebergs: Towards a theory of biased globalization, Review of Economic Studies 74, 237-253.
- McCann, Ph. (2005) Transport costs and new economic geography, Journal of Economic Geography 5, 305-318.
- Pflüger and Südekum (2009) Subsidizing Firm Entry in Open Economy. IZA working paper.
- Rudolph, S, 2010, The Gravity Equation With Micro-founded Trade Costs. Working Paper.
Tuesday, January 11, 2011
Congratulating Someone On Their Mothers Birthday
The display driver no longer met ...
It started slowly in the late evening ... I had to train my 3 accounts are still active and pending since I still acorns in Orgrimmar.
Suddenly, a freeze, then the screen becomes monochromatic, and it's back to normal with this message oracular bottom of the screen: "The display driver no longer met and was recovered. "
Fifteen minutes later, here we go again.
There I say that the system saturates and it is quite late, I can go sleep in peace.
The next day I start my activities wowesques by a small tower at the auction house. I connect a single account, and I barely have time to click on the goblin we go again. Devil!
Better ... Whatever the application doing some 3D I use, it crashes sooner or later. And it can lead to a super blue screen if I insist.
I check. No windows update since early December. Other than that no changes have been made on my PC. So why now? Pourqueha?
I dig through all the system logs, I uninstall the driver, reinstalled, lit a candle to Bill Gates and another to ATI, I use the default driver offered by Windows, the brand new download from the manufacturer's website. Nothing helps.
Only thing: playing WoW on one account and 800 * 600 minimum details, I can play. Obviously I have a window size of a postage stamp, because if I enlarge the window crash is assured. In short, it does not want to read the texts of quests, but it works pretty good enough for me to finish the leveling of shus before their account expires. That way it will be a standard for his team when I resume the multi.
After that I'll be able to deal a bit harder to make me a budget to buy a new PC. Yes, because after all tests and checks that I made I've been thinking about a hardware problem, probably the video card. And they're not evil, it is the newest component of ancestral my PC. So as to do so, we will change everything.
It started slowly in the late evening ... I had to train my 3 accounts are still active and pending since I still acorns in Orgrimmar.
Suddenly, a freeze, then the screen becomes monochromatic, and it's back to normal with this message oracular bottom of the screen: "The display driver no longer met and was recovered. "
Fifteen minutes later, here we go again.
There I say that the system saturates and it is quite late, I can go sleep in peace.
The next day I start my activities wowesques by a small tower at the auction house. I connect a single account, and I barely have time to click on the goblin we go again. Devil!
Better ... Whatever the application doing some 3D I use, it crashes sooner or later. And it can lead to a super blue screen if I insist.
I check. No windows update since early December. Other than that no changes have been made on my PC. So why now? Pourqueha?
I dig through all the system logs, I uninstall the driver, reinstalled, lit a candle to Bill Gates and another to ATI, I use the default driver offered by Windows, the brand new download from the manufacturer's website. Nothing helps.
Only thing: playing WoW on one account and 800 * 600 minimum details, I can play. Obviously I have a window size of a postage stamp, because if I enlarge the window crash is assured. In short, it does not want to read the texts of quests, but it works pretty good enough for me to finish the leveling of shus before their account expires. That way it will be a standard for his team when I resume the multi.
After that I'll be able to deal a bit harder to make me a budget to buy a new PC. Yes, because after all tests and checks that I made I've been thinking about a hardware problem, probably the video card. And they're not evil, it is the newest component of ancestral my PC. So as to do so, we will change everything.
Wednesday, January 5, 2011
Can Orange Juice Be Drunk When You Have Phlegm
Monday, January 3, 2011
Fucibet Cream For Thin Skin
Conference Walras
Happy New Year to everyone (and good luck for those who will soon be finished, at ditto for those who will correct them). Here are three videos
a conference that we held at Pau on general equilibrium models:
a conference that we held at Pau on general equilibrium models:
- Renato Flores, " CGE is Dead - Long Live CGE ? "
- Michel Juillard," Estimating DSGE Models Observed With Real-Time Data Expectation "
- Decaluwe Bernard, André Lemelin," A Walrasian look at current account balances: CGE models With International Financial Assets. "
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)